I don't understand this paragraph. If Footlocker was okay with $50 profit/shoe, why do they need to claim $75 profit/shoe in their costs per shoe go up? The costs of handling the shoes, retail space, advertising, and labor are all fixed.
I don't understand this paragraph. If Footlocker was okay with $50 profit/shoe, why do they need to claim $75 profit/shoe in their costs per shoe go up? The costs of handling the shoes, retail space, advertising, and labor are all fixed.
The market cares about dollar returned vs dollar invested. If some piece in the middle of the chain goes up and end customer prices go up as well, that doesn’t directly affect investors at all.
The way it could and likely will affect investors is if people start buying fewer shoes, but that is a different process than what you are describing.
If I’m off base can you help me understand what you are saying?
Think in the extreme. $1 billion can probably earn more in a saving account than as a shoe that generates $50 profit after 2 weeks.
-Some of their costs are in fact linear based on the cost of the item.
Inventory cost doubles, perhaps now they have to take out higher interest debt to finance that. Things like insurance would also at least double.
Transaction fees (like card fees at about ~2%) and other parts (like returns risk) also increase linearly.
-Reduced sales due to increased prices.
If an item is less affordable people buy less of them. Theft will also go up. If trainers were $100 a week ago and are now $200 - you will sell less, they will be stolen more.
All in you actually do need more than the fixed $50 of margin if the wholesale cost of the item changes from $50 to $100 - it may actually be that $100 is the correct number, or even too little - sales volume would concern me the most, particularly on this 'luxury' item.
Now this analogy has a LOT of problems but the point is it directly affects investors, even if the interpolations inbetween are imperfect.
All that being said, tariffs drive up the cost of living, which drives up wages, which makes everything more expensive.
I've never found Nikes that work for me, but Brooks seem custom made for me personally, so that's what I get. They're about the same price as my wife’s Nikes.
I hope you can see how spending $75 to make $150 revenue and $75 in profit is a much better position than spending $50 to make $100 in revenue and $50 in profit, if you are limited to how many transactions you can make in a day by physical infrastructure.
I think it's understandable for the store to charge more for their shoes, and for the stores to make more than $50/profit per shoe to cover higher capital investment and increased risk of loss, but I don't understand the logical leap where the store now can make 50% more profit per shoe.
Another perspective is that Footlocker would sell you those $25 Nikes for $300 if they could-- but if they tried, someone else would get active in the retail business and invest into a slightly less profitable operation (with lower margins) to eat into their market share.
But if the costs for everyone rise, raising the prices proportionally (instead of by fixed amount) makes total sense because it is not really gonna cost you market share (only decrease total market volume depending on consumer price sensitivity).
Note: We just observed those exact dynamics with Covid/Ukraine driven price increases, where retailers and other middlemen actually came out really good instead of sacrificing their margins to keep consumer costs down.
If you spend more money and get a proportional increase in quality, that's not luxury. A luxury good occurs when the marginal increase in quality cannot be justified by the increase in price. For example, you could buy a quartz Casio for $25 that's more accurate than a $10,000 mechanical Rolex. Both tell you the same time.
Let's say Foot Locker tries to keep the same absolute profit $50 and retails the shoes for $125 instead of the previous $100.
Now demand goes down, because more people will skip a new pair of sneakers. So Foot Locker's absolute profit goes down.
But they still have the same fixed retail space, advertising, and labor as you said.
So to try to keep their profitability, they need to increase the price more, which reduces demand even more, but it settles somewhere higher. And the place it settles (where total absolute profit is maximized) tends to be around the same 100% markup as before.
It doesn't need to be exactly the same, but as a general rule of thumb, these things do tend to work in proportional terms rather than absolute terms. And we're fortunate they do, because when manufacturing costs fall, that means absolute profit per unit can fall as well (while percentage remains the same), because it's made up for by more people buying.
I would think that specialised and expensive shoes have less markup than cheaper and more common shoes. But if the cheaper and more common shoes become 50% more expensive then there aren’t really any cheap shoes left to feed the bottom line…
All of that would typically be tied together as inventory cost (aside from theft, though some people do).
Lots of fascinating things in retail. Around half of all theft will be from your own employees, for example.
So to have the same quality of life, you expect higher returns.
Which mean that you will choose to invest into companies that offers a better return, and for that, these companies will have raise their prices, which in turn, spirals into additional price raises.
People will go and shop around for the best price on a $300 item, but for a $10 item they'll buy whatever's infront of them, so long as it's not clearly outrageous.
(If it's not bought on credit, there is still opportunity cost, since that money could have been used for something else.)
Yes investors look for maximal returns, but those are limited. Fundamentally the ceiling is set by demand and by your competitor's prices.
Plus, higher secondary market prices drive demand for the less desirable shoes as everyone can't afford to spend a week's wages on a pair of shoes but can stretch their budget for the still-kind-of-cool models. I'd go so far as to say the secondary market prices drive more demand for the lesser models as the cool kids want to be seen wearing what the rich cool kids are wearing.
I'm sure they spend a lot of time discussing what price they can charge without people openly revolting against their 'predatory pricing' strategies.
A lot of the costs come from bidding against other retailers for employees and retail space. If you don't make as much as the rival retailer they'll outbid you.
You can sometimes get around that by buying direct from the internet.
For example, you may announce to public markets that your profit has increased $10M despite margins eroding from 50% to 30%. You will likely be punished in terms of stock price. This is because you sold a lot more or trimmed some expenses (which is short-term good) but you are also now more risky because if sales decrease you will more easily run into trouble breaking even/covering operating costs (which is long-term bad).
So basically the money a business uses to produce the next tranche of goods (so to speak) normally comes not from income from sales of the last tranche, but rather from external funding sources such as loans or capital injection from investors?
Is that really so common as to be universal and affect investor behavior like you suggest? Like for certain types of business, and especially for early stage businesses, I do expect this to be the case. But does it apply to the market broadly? Scary if so, since it seems like a destabilizing force.
The retailer & the wholesalers involved all have a reasonable idea about what people will pay for the products in question. The portion of that final consumer price that stays with the retailer is just the result of negotiation.
The retailer can likely buy decent alarm clocks from anyone, so alarm clock makers & wholesalers have no pricing power and the retailer can demand high margins.
But the retailer can only get Garmin from Garmin. If Garmin has done a good job promoting the brand, such that the retailer feels they have no choice but to stock it, they will have to suck it up and accept low margins.
If you sell $75 shoes, you can sell 1000 units/mo, but if your shoes are $100 you can only sell 700/mo and it will take 1.5 months to sell 1000 units.
This effectively increases fixed overheads per pair of shoes and decreases net margin per pair, given constant demand
Whereas a business that can figure out how to be paid significantly before it delivers can run on much slimmer margins.
Some extra costs are real and linear to their "factory" price (returns, insurance, stolen stuff, less people buying less shoes, so they need higher margins to survive, etc.).
On the other hand... they can raise their prices today by $whatever_tarrif_trump_mentioned, and blame trump for the price hike and pocket the extra profit.
I'm pretty sure Footlocker doesn't borrow money to pay Nike up front for inventory. Nike is smart enough to know that there's zero chance their shoes will be sold if they sit in a warehouse, so Nike might as well ship them to retailers and get paid gradually as the shoes are sold to consumers.
If the shoes don't sell, their losses can get much larger.
They need the potential to make more profit to offset this this potential for larger losses.
It's kind of like asking why Sears needs to make $200 in profit selling a refrigerator but only $2 selling a t-shirt.
Because that's just how it works...
Food and clothing, anything with complex supply chains tend to be cost based pricing. As a rule of thumb, it's x3, maybe x4 for a well-branded item like Nike or Calvin Klein. Most innovations are on supply chain. E-commerce was such a big thing because it could cut out one middle man and lead to 30% price cuts or profit margins, and yet all these online shops ended up appearing in malls anyway.
Software is price based costing because there's no fancy supply chain. iPhones may be somewhere in the middle, hardware tends to have the worst of both worlds - high fixed costs and lots of middle men.
A McDonald's may have franchises and may own some restaurants internally, but they don't want to lose money, so they may base it on the lower profit margins - it makes no sense for a burger in one spot to be $4 and a burger in the franchise to be $5; both need to be $5.
Generally luxury brand do use more expensive parts, whether or not those parts add to the quality. And they do have higher profit margins. But the retailers, distributors, etc still take a 30% cut or so. And in the end, Louis Vuitton is still probably making lower margins than Plants vs Zombies.
The general point is that additional cash is tied up in shoes which cannot do something else. Who bears the burden of the loss of that additional cash changes over time (Nike to Footlocker to consumers) but the burden is bourn.
(And that's before you count the impact of the inevitable reduction in unit sales. There're various kinds of overhead that don't scale linearly units sold, or that have a long lag before scaling, or have a significantly-sized step function in the scaling.)
BTW, where did the cash go? Oh yeah, into the hands of the US federal government. We have a word for that: tax.