Most active commenters
  • sudosysgen(4)
  • pfdietz(3)

←back to thread

275 points swores | 30 comments | | HN request time: 0.68s | source | bottom
1. streptomycin ◴[] No.40173514[source]
Its own bill for landmark trials of a four-drug combination treatment for drug-resistant tuberculosis came to €34m (£29m).

Okay, how does that compare to what pharma companies spend? The article cites some unrelated numbers, doesn't actually compare.

A quick Google search says:

The average cost of phase 1, 2, and 3 clinical trials across therapeutic areas is around $4, 13, and 20 million respectively.

So... not really that different? What's the big deal here?

replies(5): >>40173613 #>>40173658 #>>40173916 #>>40173982 #>>40176577 #
2. throwaway35777 ◴[] No.40173613[source]
Don't successful drugs also have to pay for the failed trials?
replies(4): >>40173936 #>>40173983 #>>40173995 #>>40174204 #
3. Retric ◴[] No.40173658[source]
The S.

“Its own bill for landmark trialS of a four-drug combination treatment for drug-resistant tuberculosis came to €34m (£29m)”

You’re also looking at the cost from from 2015 to 2016 where a single phase 3 trial was already 20m and $41,117 per patient. https://www.linkedin.com/pulse/clinical-trial-budget-example...

replies(2): >>40173870 #>>40175188 #
4. nickff ◴[] No.40173870[source]
I don’t understand the difference you’re trying to point out. You’re both talking about the total cost for a testing a combination of drugs which required multiple phases, each of which is deemed a different trial. Am I wrong? What difference are you trying to highlight with the “s”?
replies(1): >>40174374 #
5. ◴[] No.40173936[source]
6. downrightmike ◴[] No.40173982[source]
How much of that is Universities doing all the leg work?
replies(1): >>40174164 #
7. kurthr ◴[] No.40173983[source]
And also for failed executive pay, and failed lobbying, which are much more expensive. In some cases (like Aduhelm) the marketing started before it was shown to have efficacy... so you have to pay for that very expensive failure too.

https://www.washingtonpost.com/business/2024/03/08/eli-lilly...

8. jrsdav ◴[] No.40173995[source]
This is essentially true. Pharma is incredibly expensive (for lots of different reasons), with R&D taking up a huge portion of those costs.

So yes, it's safe to assume that part of the accounting around those published costs in the billions are all of the failed candidates that never even made it to trials (the failure rate varies depending on the area of biology and the type of drug, but it's generally around 9 out of every 10 candidates [1]. By the time you get to trials, that ratio gets even more abysmal).

Disclaimer -- I work for Recursion, a company built around this very problem.

- [1]: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S221138352...

- [2]: https://www.recursion.com

replies(2): >>40174177 #>>40174706 #
9. ceejayoz ◴[] No.40174012[source]
See also: Hollywood accounting. It's fairly easy to make something look expensive if you put your mind to it.
replies(1): >>40174119 #
10. lotsofpulp ◴[] No.40174119{3}[source]
Not applicable here because no one is discussing drug companies negotiating percentage commissions with their scientists.

If Novartis was committing fraud by misstating expenses, they would be harming their own executives who get paid in equity. And if they were inflating expenses, they would, eventually, get beat by Merck/Pfizer/Lilly/myriad other competitors.

Edit to respond to below comment:

Hollywood accounting is not fraud because there are no laws requiring media makers to categorize and report expenses and income a certain way for the purposes of satisfying compensation agreements with their vendors (actors/producers/directors/etc). It all depends on each individual contract.

A publicly listed business, however, has to comply with myriad rules regarding reporting of cash flow and assets, so it is always nonsensical to bring up Hollywood accounting when discussing official financial figures reported to the SEC.

replies(1): >>40174176 #
11. streptomycin ◴[] No.40174164[source]
Not much, universities basically never pay for clinical trials.
replies(1): >>40174775 #
12. ceejayoz ◴[] No.40174176{4}[source]
Look expensive and actually expensive aren't the same, nor is creative accounting always fraud. That's the entire point of Hollywood accounting (which, in the Hollywood example, helps equity like Disney shareholders).
13. mc32 ◴[] No.40174177{3}[source]
R&D takes lots, but so does compliance --for good reason. But compliance costs a lot of money, directly and indirectly. Lots of people, lots of inefficient processes, etc.
14. darth_avocado ◴[] No.40174204[source]
Yes. They also have to pay for the $4.2B the companies spend on lobbying efforts in 2023.

https://www.nbcnews.com/investigations/lobbyists-spent-recor...

replies(2): >>40174612 #>>40176590 #
15. darby_eight ◴[] No.40174205[source]
It's almost like the market is extremely poorly suited for developing drugs
replies(1): >>40174480 #
16. Retric ◴[] No.40174374{3}[source]
Each of those different phases would have cost ~26 million (30% inflation on 2015 prices).
17. nradov ◴[] No.40174480{3}[source]
Do we have examples of non-market systems that have proven to be consistently more effective for developing drugs?
replies(1): >>40175248 #
18. ProjectArcturis ◴[] No.40174612{3}[source]
Seems like a lot, but in the context of $200B spent on R&D, 2% spent on warding off confiscation is probably money well spent.
19. tomrod ◴[] No.40174706{3}[source]
Why do the phase testing not prevent overindexing failed projects?
20. larkost ◴[] No.40174775{3}[source]
This is true, but it should also be pointed out here that Universities are where almost of all the initial research into finding and vetting candidate drugs happens, mostly on grants from the government. On the whole that is enormously costly, and the drug companies only step in to develop the drug once the lab tests are promising.

It used to be that all of the profits went to the drug companies, but more recently Universities have started to claim a portion of the patent royalties, and thus the profits. I believe the first big example of this is the University of Wisconsin's royalties on Warfarin (blood thinner used as medicine in humans, and in large doses as a rat killer).

21. cameldrv ◴[] No.40175188[source]
The super high clinical trial costs also mean problems for any drug that isn't expected to have a large effect size, because it's hard to get statistical significance.

Some trials have been controversially going for a surrogate endpoint, which makes the stats easier since you can get a continuous variable instead of a binary one, but that's also how you get aducanumab, which reduces amyloid plaque, but it's unclear if it actually helps in alzheimers. Despite this they charge $56k a year.

22. sudosysgen ◴[] No.40175248{4}[source]
Yes, universities and public research labs. What they aren't effective at, however, is financing trials, so unless we find a way to overhaul that issue we have to deal with pharma companies.
replies(1): >>40175870 #
23. pfdietz ◴[] No.40175870{5}[source]
Yes, they are very effective at developing drugs, if you ignore all the necessary expensive steps, steps that often show the drug is worthless.
replies(1): >>40176369 #
24. sudosysgen ◴[] No.40176369{6}[source]
Most drugs are shown to be worthless way before any clinical trial, and while yes they are expensive, so is fundamental research. By only looking at what pharma companies do, you skip just as many very expensive necessary steps that often show the drug is worthless.
replies(1): >>40177087 #
25. refurb ◴[] No.40176577[source]
> The average cost of phase 1, 2, and 3 clinical trials across therapeutic areas is around $4, 13, and 20 million respectively.

Average cost of a phase 3 trial is a terrible representation of costs.

Not all phase 3 trials are equal. For something like TB, the trial can be relatively small (huundreds of patients), and short (months). For something like heart disease drugs, the trials might be massive (tends of thousands of patients) and very long (years).

Anyone can call a CRO (contract research organization) up and ask what they charged for phase 3 trials. Last I talked to them it was ~$15,000/patient/year.

It's pretty easy to do the math based on that. A heart disease drug with 10,000 patients lasting 3 years will cost $450M.

26. refurb ◴[] No.40176590{3}[source]
Uhhh.. $4.2B is all lobbying, not just pharma?
27. pfdietz ◴[] No.40177087{7}[source]
And most of the drugs that advance to clinical trials wash out there as well.
replies(1): >>40177492 #
28. sudosysgen ◴[] No.40177492{8}[source]
Yes. You are the one that's trying to argue that pushing past clinical trials is riskier than fundamental research, so I don't understand your argument. You have to argue that clinical trials are riskier, not that they are risky at all. I suspect we would agree that fundamental research is actually far riskier.

Universities and research labs are really quite good at coming up with drugs that are good candidates for clinical trials, so the issue is not an issue of development, it's an issue of aligning incentive and finance to get them to pay for trials, which is not currently possible. This is a problem that is likely solvable.

Showing that this is not true would require you to show that private pharmas are somehow able to come up with drugs that are more likely to survive clinical trials, which is not something I believe to be true. There is some evidence on this subject - in fact, a rising percentage of drugs are invented in academia (more than 30% as of 2020), and then transferred to for-profit pharma companies that then run trials, which indicates that academia can produce new drugs more efficiently (see for example https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC8552459/), and that academic-invented drugs are as likely to succeed even when early trials are largely ran by academic institutions (https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC6226120/)

Indeed, recent data shows that a growing majority of biotech drugs are acquired from universities, and in turn those are a growing majority of newly approved drugs - a large and very profitable part of the pharma industry nowadays is to get universities to come up and screen drugs for you, and then to run them to trials. This arbitrage opportunity indicates to me that yes, publicly funded research seems to be a very efficient source of drugs.

This is even clearer when you realize that only 20% of public research funding goes towards drug development - most of it goes to the fundamental research that makes it possible to come up with drugs in the first place, something that pharma companies will never do.

replies(1): >>40179656 #
29. pfdietz ◴[] No.40179656{9}[source]
Could you argue against what I actually wrote? Thanks.

Of course the fraction of drugs that succeed after reaching clinical trials is greater than the fraction of drugs that succeed from the very beginning. What clinical trials are is very expensive. So I would not be at all surprised if most of the cost of failed drugs is from those that fail late rather than early.

replies(1): >>40180295 #
30. sudosysgen ◴[] No.40180295{10}[source]
I'm not arguing against your premise because your conclusion - that you leave implied - doesn't follow from your premise. When your argument did follow from your premise, that "all the expensive parts" is solely in the clinical trial, I did argue against your premise.

What you actually wrote in your second comment doesn't effectively argue against my point. There's no point arguing your assertion that clinical trials are expensive, they are, what you needed to argue was that it means that pharma companies are more efficient at developing drugs.

It can even be true that clinical trials are more expensive and that most of the aggregate cost from failed drugs is due to those that fail late, as well as that public research is more efficient at developing drugs.

Why? Because the likelihood that a drug fails, late of early, is a function of the drug itself - we expect that any trial of the same drug would arrive at essentially the same result. Therefore, even if the total cost of failed drugs is concentrated in those that fail late, that cost mostly has to do with the initial drug design, and I've provided quantitative data on the success rate of academic drug design, which is comparable or better than private drug design.

Therefore, the evidence is that academia can actually design drugs that have a competitively low expected cost from late failure.

Market dynamics also support this : a major and growing portion of new drug approvals are exactly this : academia designs a drug that has a competitively low cost from late clinical trial failure, a biotech company buys the rights to it after academia makes a compelling case, the trials succeed, and the biotech company makes a large expected profit.

So, even if your hypothesis is that most of the cost is from drugs that fail do fail late, it doesn't challenge the idea that academia is good at discovering drugs, because the drugs academia discover aren't more likely to fail late, according to the data I found and provided.

Also, you have to show that the majority of cost is from drugs that fail late : that doesn't seem true at all. The total cost of all clinical trials in the US is around 7B$ a year (https://www.clinicalleader.com/doc/considerations-for-improv...). As you correctly imply, this is a cost that is borne in large majority by the private sector. However, the other costs that are borne almost exclusively by the public sector and that are a necessary additional cost to add to the cost of drug development, is fundamental research, which provides new targets and modalities that are a necessary precursor to drug research. That accounts for the majority of the NIH budget, which itself is only one of the institutions that funds such research, and amounts to 48B$.